-
Why studying emergence of money?
-
The question that inspired this work was:
-
what about having more than one form of money circulating?
-
Are there examples of really different kinds of money?
- Smuk is King
- “In inmates’ eyes, the organization of prison life is premised on the action of smoking; when cigarettes are taken away those social forms break down and men withdraw from contact with each other” (42)
- cigarettes govern every action; they are a fetish object
- “The fetish object is not animated by something foreign to it – human intention or social meaning – but by a spirit that seems its own. That spirit is not held to reside in matter, but rather it appears as the spirit of matter” (41)
- Psychological colors of money
- contrary to a naive view, money still brings with it the color of its provenience.
- Black money, illegally acquired, must be “laundred”;
- an unexpected windfall may end being treated differently from a bonus or an inheritance, even if the sums are equal [Zelizer1989Social]
-
Did I answer that question?
- No.
- But some of us had to look into the literature of money emergence.
-
We all know what money is; there's nothing as obvious and as engraved in our everyday life.
- Now, being a cultural construct - an artefact - means that, again unlike food or sleep, we can ask some theoretical questions about money
-
Previous Work
-
Running a research of simulative models of money emergence, I found a much much lower number of papers than I expected.
- Models by game theorist use 3 (three?) different goods - Kiyotaki and Wright 1989
-
Between simulation models, the classic seems to be Yasutomi (1994)
-
Some other went out in recent years - but oversimplified
- One with multiple monies but only by spatial constraints
-
Others recent ones are difficult to retrieve
- There is an interesting (and inaccessible) one using "double networks"
-
Replication of Yatsutomi's simulation
-
Why?
- Bruce Edmonds and David Hales (2003): Replication, Replication and Replication
-
What is the basic idea of the model?
-
Agents produce one kind of good and want another.
- They barter only when they are randomly matched - a double coincidence of wants, which is unlikely to happen even with small numbers (50 agents in Yasutomi's paper)
-
So, a "wanted" vector is introduced in which the agents keep track of goods that have been requested but they were unable to offer.
- Example of a desired vector
- If a value gets over a fixed threshold, then that good gets accepted for exchange.
-
Results
- Money emerges for a range of threshold values.
-
Results by topology
-
Full connection
-
Figures
-
time of money emergence
- zoom of the same
-
Random topology
-
Figure
-
opt
- consumption
-
Star topology
-
Figure
-
opt
- consumption
-
Preferential attchment network
-
figures
-
Opt
- consumed
-
Conclusions
- Another characteristic of social networks: they may be the ideal place to allow money to emerge from barter.
- Can we stretch the model to something else? Like exchange of ideas?
-
Yasutomi showed a nice model of money emergence with a fully connected topology. Relaxing this assumption we found that
- If we simply use a random network, we see faster convergence on one exchange item as money - but also a greatly depressed volume of exchanges.
- A special shape like the star-shaped network shows this in the extreme - money emerges quickly and predictably, but the volume of exchanges never flares up.
- Scale free networks share both characteristics of having a preferential point and a higher connection level; from the simulations in this paper, they seem to be an ideal compromise between the star network and the random - exchanges are systematically higher and money emergence stronger than with their network counterparts.
- So, inverting the point of view, maybe there is another reason that we have so many scale free networks in the social world - because scale free networks allow for both quick convergence - coordination - and volume of exchange.